PlumX Metrics
Embed PlumX Metrics

Group decisions in biodiversity conservation: Implications from game theory

PLoS ONE, ISSN: 1932-6203, Vol: 5, Issue: 5, Page: e10688
2010
  • 21
    Citations
  • 0
    Usage
  • 172
    Captures
  • 0
    Mentions
  • 0
    Social Media
Metric Options:   Counts1 Year3 Year

Metrics Details

Article Description

Background: Decision analysis and game theory [1,2] have proved useful tools in various biodiversity conservation planning and modeling contexts [3-5]. This paper shows how game theory may be used to inform group decisions in biodiversity conservation scenarios by modeling conflicts between stakeholders to identify Pareto-inefficient Nash equilibria. These are cases in which each agent pursuing individual self-interest leads to a worse outcome for all, relative to other feasible outcomes. Three case studies from biodiversity conservation contexts showing this feature are modeled to demonstrate how game-theoretical representation can inform group decision-making. Methodology and Principal Findings: The mathematical theory of games is used to model three biodiversity conservation scenarios with Pareto-inefficient Nash equilibria: (i) a two-agent case involving wild dogs in South Africa; (ii) a three-agent raptor and grouse conservation scenario from the United Kingdom; and (iii) an n-agent fish and coral conservation scenario from the Philippines. In each case there is reason to believe that traditional mechanism-design solutions that appeal to material incentives may be inadequate, and the game-theoretical analysis recommends a resumption of further deliberation between agents and the initiation of trust-and confidence-building measures. Conclusions and Significance: Game theory can and should be used as a normative tool in biodiversity conservation contexts: identifying scenarios with Pareto-inefficient Nash equilibria enables constructive action in order to achieve (closer to) optimal conservation outcomes, whether by policy solutions based on mechanism design or otherwise. However, there is mounting evidence [6] that formal mechanism-design solutions may backfire in certain cases. Such scenarios demand a return to group deliberation and the creation of reciprocal relationships of trust. © 2010 Frank, Sarkar.

Bibliographic Details

http://www.scopus.com/inward/record.url?partnerID=HzOxMe3b&scp=77956272675&origin=inward; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/20523732; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t006; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t006; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t003; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t003; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t002; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t002; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t004; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t004; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t001; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t001; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t005; http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t005; https://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t002; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t002; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t001; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t001; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t005; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t005; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t003; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t003; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t006; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t006; https://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t004; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/figure?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t004; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t001; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t003; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; https://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/file?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688&type=printable; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t002; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t005; http://journals.plos.org/plosone/article?id=10.1371%2Fjournal.pone.0010688; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t004; http://journals.plos.org/plosone/article?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; http://dx.plos.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688.t006; http://www.plosone.org/article/metrics/info:doi/10.1371/journal.pone.0010688; http://journals.plos.org/plosone/article/file?id=10.1371/journal.pone.0010688&type=printable

David M. Frank; Sahotra Sarkar; Raphaël Arlettaz

Public Library of Science (PLoS)

Multidisciplinary

Provide Feedback

Have ideas for a new metric? Would you like to see something else here?Let us know